What is meant by cooperative strategy?

  1. Last updated
  2. Save as PDF
  • Page ID43181
    • What is meant by cooperative strategy?
    • Andrew Barkley
    • Kansas State University via New Prairie Press/Kansas State University Libraries

    \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \) \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash {#1}}} \)\(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)\(\newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

    The cooperative strategy is defined as the best joint outcome for both players together.

    Cooperative Strategy = A strategy that leads to the highest joint payoff for all players.

    Thus, the cooperative strategy is identical to collusion, where players work together to achieve the best joint outcome. In the Prisoner’s Dilemma (Figure 6.1), the cooperative outcome is found by summing the two players’ outcomes together, and finding the outcome that has the smallest jail sentence for the prisoners together: \(\text{(NOT, NOT) } = (3, 3)\).

    This outcome is the collusive solution, which provides the best outcome if the prisoners could make a joint decision and stick with it. Of course, there is always the temptation to cheat on the agreement, where each player does better for themselves, at the expense of the other prisoner.

    Similarly, the cooperative outcome in the advertising game (Figure 6.2) is \(\text{(AD, AD) } = (20, 20)\). This outcome provides the highest profits \((= 40\) million USD) to both firms. Note that the advertising game is not a prisoner’s dilemma, since there is no incentive to cheat once the cooperative solution has been achieved.

    Game Theory Example: Steak Pricing Game

    A pricing game for steaks if shown in Figure \(\PageIndex{1}\). In this game, two beef processors, Tyson and JBS, are determining what price to charge for steaks. Suppose that these two firms are the major players in this steak market, and the outcomes depend on the strategies of both firms, since players choose which company to purchase from based on price. If both firms choose low prices, the outcome is low profits. Additional profits are earned by choosing high prices. However, when both firms have high prices, there is an incentive to undercut the other firm with a low price, to increase profits at the expense of the other firm.

    What is meant by cooperative strategy?
    Figure \(\PageIndex{1}\): Steak Pricing Game: Two Beef Firms. Outcomes in million USD.

    Steak Pricing Game: Dominant Strategy

    (1) If \(\text{TYSON LOW, JBS}\) should \(\text{LOW } (2 > 0)\)

    (2) If \(\text{TYSON HIGH, JBS}\) should \(\text{LOW } (12 > 10)\)

    …the dominant strategy for \(\text{TYSON}\) is \(\text{LOW}\).

    (3) If \(\text{JBS LOW, TYSON}\) should \(\text{LOW } (2 > 0)\)

    (4) If \(\text{JBS HIGH, TYSON}\) should \(\text{LOW } (12 > 10)\)

    … the dominant strategy for \(\text{JBS}\) is \(\text{LOW}\).

    The Equilibrium in Dominant Strategies for the Steak Pricing game is \(\text{(LOW, LOW)}\). This is an unexpected result, since it is a less desirable scenario than \(\text{(HIGH, HIGH)}\) for both firms. We have seen that an Equilibrium in Dominant Strategies is also a Nash Equilibrium and a Minimax Equilibrium. These results will be checked in what follows.

    Steak Pricing Game: Nash Equilibrium

    (1) Outcome \(= \text{(LOW, LOW)}\)

    (a) Is \(\text{LOW}\) best for \(\text{JBS}\) given \(\text{TYSON LOW}\)? Yes.

    (b) Is \(\text{LOW}\) best for \(\text{TYSON}\) given \(\text{JBS LOW}\)? Yes.

    …\(\text{(LOW, LOW)}\) is a Nash Equilibrium.

    (2) Outcome \(= \text{(LOW, HIGH)}\)

    (a) Is \(\text{LOW}\) best for \(\text{JBS}\) given \(\text{TYSON HIGH}\)? Yes.

    (b) Is \(\text{HIGH}\) best for \(\text{TYSON}\) given \(\text{JBS LOW}\)? No.

    …\(\text{(LOW, HIGH)}\) is not a Nash Equilibrium.

    (3) Outcome \(= \text{(HIGH, LOW)}\)

    (a) Is \(\text{HIGH}\) best for \(\text{JBS}\) given \(\text{TYSON LOW}\)? No.

    (b) Is \(\text{LOW}\) best for \(\text{TYSON}\) given \(\text{JBS HIGH}\)? Yes.

    …\(\text{(HIGH, LOW)}\) is not a Nash Equilibrium.

    (4) Outcome \(= \text{(HIGH, HIGH)}\)

    (a) Is \(\text{HIGH}\) best for \(\text{JBS}\) given \(\text{TYSON HIGH}\)? No.

    (b) Is \(\text{HIGH}\) best for \(\text{TYSON}\) given \(\text{JBS HIGH}\)? No.

    …\(\text{(HIGH, HIGH)}\) is not a Nash Equilibrium.

    Therefore, there is only one Nash Equilibrium in the Steak Pricing game: \(\text{(LOW, LOW)}\).

    Steak Pricing Game: Maximin Equilibrium (Safety First)

    (1) \(\text{JBS}\)

    (a) If \(\text{LOW}\), worst payoff \(= 2\).

    (b) If \(\text{HIGH}\), worst payoff \(= 0\).

    …\(\text{JBS}\)’ Maximin Strategy is \(\text{LOW } (0 < 2)\).

    (2) \(\text{TYSON}\)

    (a) If \(\text{LOW}\), worst payoff \(= 2\).

    (b) If \(\text{HIGH}\), worst payoff \(= 0\).

    …\(\text{TYSON}\)’s Maximin Strategy is \(\text{LOW } (0 < 2)\).

    The Maximin Equilibrium in the Steak Pricing game is \(\text{(LOW, LOW)}\). Interestingly, if both firms cooperated, they could achieve much higher profits.

    Steak Pricing Game: Cooperative Equilibrium (Collusion)

    Both JBS and Tyson can see that if they were to cooperate, either explicitly or implicitly, profits would increase significantly. The cooperative outcome is \(\text{(HIGH, HIGH) } = (10,10)\). This is the outcome with the highest combined profits. Both firms are better off in this outcome, but each firm has an incentive to cheat on the agreement to increase profits from 10 m USD to 12 m USD.

    What is cooperative strategy example?

    Example of Cooperative Strategy Customer travelling from Europe to Australia can travel through connecting flights of different airlines working together. Hence, this concludes the definition of Cooperative Strategies along with its overview.

    What is the main aim of cooperative strategy?

    Cooperative strategy is the attempt by organizations to realize their objectives through cooperation with other organizations, rather than in competition with them. It focuses on the benefits that can be gained through cooperation and how the management of cooperation can realize these benefits.

    What are corporate strategies?

    A corporate strategy is a long-term plan that outlines clear goals for a company. While the objective of each goal may differ, the ultimate purpose of a corporate strategy is to improve the company. A company's corporate strategy may be to focus on sales, growth or leadership.

    What are the cooperative competitive strategies?

    The Cooperative/Competitive Strategy Scale yielded three subscale factors: (a) motivation to use competitive strategies to achieve success, (b) motivation to use cooperative strategies to achieve success, and (c) motivation to avoid competitive strategies and their successful outcomes.